|
|
xiii | |
Preface |
|
xv | |
Acknowledgements |
|
xvii | |
Introduction |
|
1 | (13) |
|
1 The K that wouldn't go away |
|
|
1 | (1) |
|
|
2 | (2) |
|
|
4 | (2) |
|
4 Idealizations and the method of economics: some historical background |
|
|
6 | (5) |
|
|
11 | (3) |
|
1 A brief exposition of res witching and capital reversing |
|
|
14 | (8) |
|
|
14 | (1) |
|
|
15 | (3) |
|
3 Characteristic propositions of neoclassical production theory |
|
|
18 | (1) |
|
4 Perversities and anomalies |
|
|
18 | (4) |
|
2 The background of the debate: some history |
|
|
22 | (6) |
|
1 Robinson's research programme |
|
|
22 | (2) |
|
2 Discontinuities in the recent history of economic thought |
|
|
24 | (4) |
|
3 Clouds in the neoclassical sky |
|
|
28 | (19) |
|
1 Robinson defines the problem |
|
|
28 | (10) |
|
2 Champernowne's solution |
|
|
38 | (3) |
|
3 Robinson returns to the problem |
|
|
41 | (3) |
|
|
44 | (3) |
|
4 Taking methodological stock (I) |
|
|
47 | (19) |
|
1 The Polish idealization model |
|
|
47 | (6) |
|
2 Back to the capital theory debate |
|
|
53 | (1) |
|
3 Correspondence and factualization |
|
|
54 | (2) |
|
4 An excursion into the philosophy of science |
|
|
56 | (3) |
|
5 Better roughly right than precisely wrong? |
|
|
59 | (2) |
|
6 An example of correspondence |
|
|
61 | (5) |
|
5 Triumph and crisis of the neoclassical production model |
|
|
66 | (18) |
|
|
67 | (10) |
|
2 Crisis for the neoclassical model |
|
|
77 | (7) |
|
6 Taking methodological stock (II) |
|
|
84 | (9) |
|
1 The antipodean idealization model |
|
|
84 | (2) |
|
2 Aiming at a complete model of idealizations |
|
|
86 | (7) |
|
|
93 | (17) |
|
1 A little theorem with big consequences |
|
|
94 | (3) |
|
|
97 | (13) |
|
|
110 | (19) |
|
|
111 | (3) |
|
2 Brown pursues the trail |
|
|
114 | (6) |
|
3 More neoclassical resources are mobilized |
|
|
120 | (9) |
|
9 Taking methodological stock (III) |
|
|
129 | (9) |
|
|
129 | (5) |
|
2 Strategies and likelihoods |
|
|
134 | (1) |
|
3 AIM and PIM reconsidered |
|
|
135 | (1) |
|
|
136 | (2) |
|
10 The role of mathematics |
|
|
138 | (22) |
|
1 Mathematics as a neutral instrument |
|
|
138 | (2) |
|
2 Mathematics as an integral part of scientific discovery |
|
|
140 | (4) |
|
3 The adoption of mathematics by economists |
|
|
144 | (1) |
|
4 The dialectics of mathematics and science |
|
|
145 | (2) |
|
|
147 | (13) |
|
11 Taking methodological stock (IV) |
|
|
160 | (7) |
|
1 The sorcerer's apprentices |
|
|
160 | (2) |
|
2 From the science of mathematics to the mathematics of science |
|
|
162 | (1) |
|
|
162 | (2) |
|
|
164 | (1) |
|
5 Proofs, programmes, and strategies |
|
|
165 | (2) |
|
|
167 | (21) |
|
|
167 | (1) |
|
2 The ironies explained: sleepwalking on the object level |
|
|
168 | (1) |
|
3 Empirical versus formal arguments: sleepwalking on the meta level |
|
|
169 | (2) |
|
4 What do research programmes do? |
|
|
171 | (2) |
|
5 Presuppositions as heuristics |
|
|
173 | (1) |
|
6 Modelling presuppositions |
|
|
174 | (5) |
|
7 Presuppositions and the logic of discovery |
|
|
179 | (1) |
|
8 Methodological spin-off |
|
|
180 | (1) |
|
9 Different models for different purposes? Three types of pluralism |
|
|
181 | (2) |
|
10 Idealization: between instrument and explanation |
|
|
183 | (1) |
|
|
184 | (4) |
Bibliography |
|
188 | (14) |
Index |
|
202 | |